Skip to main content
  • Original Article
  • Open access
  • Published:

Money also is sunny in a retiree’s world: financial incentives and work after retirement

Abstract

This paper assesses the impact of financial incentives on working after retirement. The empirical analysis is based on a large administrative individual career data set that includes information about 2% of all German employees subject to social security or in marginal employment until age 67 and their employers in the period 1975–2014. We use the classical labor supply model and differentiate between the impact of (potential) labor and non-labor (pension entitlements) income. A Heckman-type two step selection model corrects for endogeneity. We show that labor income has a positive and non-labor income a negative impact on the decision to work after retirement. Especially individuals who can substantially increase their earnings in comparison to their pension entitlements accordingly have a higher probability to work. Men are more attracted by labor earnings incentives than women. Also individuals who work until retirement are easier attracted to work after retirement by higher labor income than those with gaps between employment exit and retirement. Our results allow the calculation of the impact of changes in taxes on labor and non-labor income and changes in earnings offers by employers on work after retirement for different demographic groups.

1 Introduction

Labor force participation of retirees increased strongly in most European countries in recent years (Eurofound 2012; Hofäcker and Naumann 2015). On average, the employment rate for individuals aged between 65 and 74 years has risen from 5.2% in 2002 to 8.7% (an increase of 67%) in 2014 in the EU-15 Countries (Rhein 2016).Footnote 1

Individual, social and work-related push and pull factors have been put forward as drivers of post-retirement employment in a dynamically developing strand of scientific literature (Anger et al. 2018; Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Büsch et al. 2010; Cahill et al. 2015; Fasbender et al. 2016; Maxin and Deller 2010; Micheel et al. 2010; Pleau and Shauman 2013; Wang et al. 2008; Westermeier 2019).

This paper concentrates on the impact of financial incentives of older individuals on their decision to work after retirement or not. More specifically, we estimate the percentage change in labor force participation after retirement in response to a percentage change in the financial situation. On the basis of a Heckman (1976, 1979) approach to correct for sample selection, we show that (potential) labor earnings are an important pull factor for the decision to engage in employment beyond retirement. We separately assess the second main financial incentive mechanism and find that there is a sizeable negative pension entitlement (non-labor income) effect on the probability of working after retirement. As a consequence, we show that the higher the ratio between (potential) post-retirement labor earnings and pension entitlements, the larger the likelihood of post-retirement employment. The second aim of the paper is the provision of empirical evidence of heterogeneous earnings elasticities between retiree groups. We show that women are less responsive to higher labor earnings than men. Especially men with low earnings before retirement have high earnings elasticities. We in addition find that individuals who use the bridge options partial retirement or unemployment before early retirement are less responsive to higher labor earnings after retirement than their counterparts who work until retirement.

This paper makes the following contributions to the literature on empirical determinants of work beyond retirement: first, we empirically assess the importance of labor earnings in comparison to non-labor income for work beyond retirement for the first time. Second, large-scale and reliable administrative social security panel data covering all types of employees except civil and military servants are used instead of small-scale and potentially specific sub-populations or survey-based data that were the basis of most relevant studies so far.Footnote 2 Third, a rich set of employer and individual characteristics allows us to control for additional determinants of work beyond retirement. Fourth, based on hypotheses, we show heterogeneities in labor earnings elasticities between men and women, employees who have their work and home in the same region or not, employees with and without a gap between employment exit and retirement, and employees with high and low earnings before retirement. The analysis of differences in elasticities between these sub-groups allows us to derive more specific implications of changes in financial incentives for these sub-groups.

2 Background

2.1 Financial situation as driver of work after retirement

There are strong indications that the individual financial situation is a key driver of work after retirement.Footnote 3 More specifically, Hochfellner and Burkert (2013) and Pleau and Shauman (2013) find a negative correlation between pension entitlements and work after retirement—Kanabar (2015) however does not find this correlation. Micheel et al. (2010) stress a negative correlation between equivalent household income before retirement and the interest in work after retirement—Engstler and Romeu-Gordo (2014) however find a u-shaped pattern for work after retirement and equivalent household income. Maestas (2010) finds a weakly positive correlation between the decision to unretire and earnings before retirement. Komp et al. (2010) and Kanabar (2015) find no correlation between working after retirement and (non-pension) wealth. Engstler and Romeu-Gordo (2014) point to the fact that higher financial pressure such as the presence of a real estate loan also can explain work after retirement.

When looking closer at the measurement of the financial situation of retirees, it becomes evident that so far no contribution on work after retirement made a distinction between labor and non-labor income. Some papers only include non-labor income after retirement such as pension entitlements (Hochfellner and Burkert 2013; Kanabar 2015). Other papers bundle up non-labor and labor income after retirement by for example using equivalent household income after retirement (Anger et al. 2018; Engstler and Romeu-Gordo 2014; Micheel et al. 2010; Pfarr and Maier 2015). A last group of papers looks at wealth or the subjective economic status before retirement (Fasbender et al. 2016; Kanabar 2015; Komp et al. 2010; Wang et al. 2008).

Empirical approaches that do not separate labor and non-labor earnings after retirement may report biased results on financial determinants of work participation after retirement. According to standard labor supply theory, labor earnings are assumed to increase work participation and non-labor income is assumed to decrease it (Cahuc et al. 2004; Blundell et al. 2007). When work has a higher reward, workers substitute leisure against work. An increase in non-labor income has a negative effect on work participation or working hours. The income effect induces employees to reduce work because they can maintain a target standard of living with lower labor burden. This paper for the first time distinguishes between income and substitution effects of work and non-work income after retirement on work participation and shows the empirical relevance of both drivers.

The extensive labor supply margin response to marginal work income changes depends on the probability density function of the distribution of reservation wages around the economy’s equilibrium. The variance in labor supply for small changes in wages around the equilibrium wage is low for the entire working-age population because relatively few people who do not work are willing or able to work for the current wage (Chetty et al. 2011). It is therefore hard to estimate reliable earnings elasticities on labor supply for the working-age population. Relatively many employees at the end of their career are closer to the margin of re-entering the labor force for available earnings opportunities, however. As the previous labor contract ends when entering retirement, all employees close to retirement have to decide whether to work in a new labor contract or not besides receiving retirement benefits. Upon retirement, labor re-entry incidence and potential extensive margin responses to labor earnings options therefore are relatively high in comparison to the earnings elasticity for the entire population (Rogerson and Wallenius 2009).

Analogously to people close to retirement, all women with a small child have to decide whether to work again or continue to provide full time childcare. As a consequence, also the extensive margin response to labor earnings incentives is relatively high (and easier to measure) for women with small children. The empirical literature on mothers with young children shows that besides non-labor financial means such as income received by other household members, childcare cost subsidies or public transfers such as parental allowance, also (potential) labor earnings are an important driver of labor market re-entry (Allègre et al. 2015; Borra 2010; Connelly 1992; Del Boca and Vuri 2007; Ribar 1992; Viitanen 2005). The empirical identification strategy to analyze financial incentives on labor supply of mothers after their parental leave period can be applied to the labor supply decision of older workers after their retirement. As a consequence, we use the Heckman selection model proposed for example by Connelly (1992) or Borra (2010) and assume that for retirees, (potential) labor earnings are an important driver for work after retirement besides non-labor earnings.

2.2 Basic model

According to the standard labor supply model, retirees maximize their utility by comparing consumption made possible by labor and non-labor income with leisure (Cahuc et al. 2004). In the case of work after retirement, individuals decide whether to work or not after they receive an old-age pension.Footnote 4 The observation period therefore starts at the earliest at the early retirement age (ERA) for those eligible for an early retirement option or at the normal retirement age (NRA) for the other employees. Figure 1 shows different possible budget lines as well as the retirees’ corresponding indifference curves. The slope of the indifference curves (UA, UB, UC, UD) defines the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure. The shape of the indifference curves corresponds to consumption and leisure being defined as “normal” goods with decreasing marginal returns.

Fig. 1
figure 1

(Source: own illustration)

Labor supply model of retirees

In this model, individual income consists of non-labor income (in our case pension entitlements) V and labor earnings W. The earnings derived from work after retirement correspond to the opportunity costs of leisure. The point where one of the retiree’s indifference curves tangents the budget line is the combination of earnings and leisure with which the retiree maximizes utility under the budget constraint.

Figure 1 shows that if potential (hourly) labor earnings after retirement are too low, the individual does not work after retirement. The maximum indifference curve, \(U_{A}\) crosses the budget line at point A and the retiree consumes only non-labor earnings V0. If (hourly) labor earnings and accordingly the slope of the budget line increase, utility is maximized at point B with UB > UA. The retiree therefore decides to work after retirement (substitution effect) and we can derive the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1

The higher the (potential) labor earnings after retirement, the greater the likelihood to work after retirement.

An increase in non-labor income from V0 to V1 results in a parallel shift of the budget line. With higher non-labor income, labor force participation decreases because the retiree can now consume the same quantity of goods when working less (income effect). In Fig. 1, the income effect is depicted by steeper indifference curves at a given leisure level with increasing V. Thus, an increase in the pension entitlements decreases the opportunity cost of leisure. In Fig. 1 an increase in the pension entitlements is illustrated as a shift from point B to point C. Note that with an increase in V that is strong enough, at a given labor earnings level, pensioners may decide to stop working. Therefore, the following hypothesis is derived:

Hypothesis 2

The higher the pension entitlements (non-labor income), the lower the likelihood to work after retirement.

Given the higher pension entitlement, V1, higher (potential) labor earnings (W2 instead of W1) are needed to incentivize the retiree to work as much as in point B (point D, for example). A higher substitution effect (higher labor earnings) has to compensate for a higher income effect (higher non-labor income) for labor market participation after retirement. Hypothesis 3 combines the first two hypotheses:

Hypothesis 3

The higher the ratio between the (potential) labor earnings after retirement and non-labor income, the greater the likelihood that the retiree works after retirement.

2.3 Heterogeneous responses to financial incentives

We now derive factors that explain differences in labor earnings elasticities for the labor force participation between retiree groups. Arguments concerning different responses of individuals to financial incentives from labor supply theory and existing empirical results on post-retirement employment are built upon to derive hypotheses that can be tested in the empirical analysis.

In the labor supply literature, a robust finding is that earnings elasticities of women exceed that of men (Bargain et al. 2014; Evers et al. 2005; Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001). The difference between gender groups is explained by the division of labor within the family (Blundell et al. 2007). According to Blau and Kahn (2007) and Mincer (1962), women substitute their time between market work, home production, and leisure, whereas men primarily substitute their time between market work and leisure. As women have closer substitutes for market work than men, they are expected to have larger earnings substitution effects. The literature therefore points out that household production increases the elasticity of labor supply because home-made goods are substitutes for commercial goods (Cahuc et al. 2004; Mincer 1962).

At first sight, the labor supply mechanisms for all individuals in working age also apply for retirees. The share of older women engaged in household production (e.g., care of relatives, childcare of grandchildren) is higher than the comparable share of men (Hank and Buber 2009). In addition, there is a second spike in household production when individuals approach retirement age. This spike is larger for women than for men, see Vargha et al. (2017). There is a decisive difference between the average individual in working age and the decision for work after retirement when calculating the employment earnings elasticities, however. Until retirement, the share of men who do not work is much smaller than the share of women (Blau and Kahn 2007). The labor market attachment of men who potentially can join the workforce therefore is lower than that of women. Hence, the earnings elasticity of males during their working age on average is lower than the earnings elasticity of females (Bastani et al. 2021). On day 1 after retirement, labor market participation of men and women is set to zero, however. As a consequence, there may be more males willing to re-enter work after retirement than females at available labor earnings given the higher home production duties of women that make labor market participation less attractive or impossible for them. In other words, the density of male retirees to re-enter employment may be higher than the density of female retirees.

Therefore, we assume that the labor earnings elasticity for old women is lower than that for old men:

Hypothesis 4

Women have lower post-retirement labor earnings elasticities than men.

Some previous papers on the decision to work after retirement look at potential differences between men and women. As financial drivers however only individual and equivalent household income before retirement as well as wealth and pension entitlements have been included but not our key variable (potential) labor earnings. Pleau (2010) and Pleau and Shauman (2013) stress that women with a high individual income before retirement more often work after retirement. Equivalent household income and wealth seem to play no role for women. For men however work after retirement is positively correlated with equivalent household income and negatively with wealth (but not individual income). Engstler and Romeu-Gordo (2014) however find an impact of pension entitlements for men only.

In Germany, there are various ways to transit from employment to retirement (Rasner and Etgeton 2014). A substantial portion of older workers have a gap between employment exit and retirement entry. This gap is called “bridge option” if individuals do not withdraw from the labor market between the exit from their last employment and retirement (Brussig 2015). There are two bridge options, an unemployment spell between work exit and (early) retirement and partial retirement. Partial retirement may mean that employees work full time for half the partial retirement period at reduced earnings and exit employment completely for the second half. The so-called block model version of partial retirement has been chosen by more than 80% of participants (Brussig 2015). A much smaller share of retirees chose the so-called continuous version of partial retirement. Here the employee reduced working-time to half during the entire partial retirement period and no gap between labor market exit and pension entry occurs.Footnote 5 Both bridge options can be used by employees after 15 contribution years to pension retirement and at least 8 years of contributions periods in the last 10 years before retirement. Bridge options therefore are not viable for employees with large labor market gaps and a low labor market attachment in general.

In both bridge options, employees usually have to accept financial disadvantages in comparison to their other (early) retirement options, but they can exit employment already before their ERA (Lorenz et al. 2020). Indeed, labor market exit age on average is between one to two years earlier for those using partial retirement or retirement after unemployment than for those choosing the early retirement options without employment gaps before retirement that also would have been available for those who used bridge options (Geyer et al. 2021).Footnote 6 For those who use both bridge paths, we hardly observe a return to regular employment before retirement. We therefore assume that employees who choose a bridge option put a relatively high value on leisure at old age and they therefore are less inclined to work after retirement. A lower inclination to work after retirement also has been found for those who did not work full time until retirement (Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Maestas 2010; Smeaton and McKay 2003)—those who use the so-called continuous version of partial retirement are a case in point for part-time work before retirement.

The argument that employees who select partial retirement have a higher value of leisure seems to be obvious because employees have to give their consent for trading earnings against an earlier employment exit (Wanger 2009). Employers therefore are more successful in nudging employees with a lower labor market attachment at old age into partial retirement. The group of employees who bridge the time between employment and retirement by unemployment may mainly consist of workers who have been dismissed against their wills and therefore their value of leisure is unclear. The German labor law especially protects employees with high tenure and/or experience against dismissal, however (Ullmann and Bothfeld 2008). In addition, many judges in labor courts are employee-friendly in dismissal disputes. As a consequence, the appeal against an involuntary dismissal before a labor court has a high success rate especially for older workers. Employers are exposed to high uncertainty with respect to the outcome of the lawsuit that easily takes more than 1 year (Ullmann and Bothfeld 2008) and they frequently face a detrimental effect on their reputation when they unilaterally dismiss older employees. Therefore, only a very small share of older employees is dismissed against their willFootnote 7 and most dismissed older employees obtain substantial severance pay (Schmähl 2003; Grund 2006). Severance and compensation payments for a dismissal or partial retirement however are subject to individual bargaining between employer and employee. Therefore, employers may prefer to nudge employees with a relatively strong preference for leisure into unemployment before early retirement because dismissing them is cheaper.Footnote 8 Our fifth hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 5

Individuals using bridge paths into retirement have lower earnings elasticities than individuals who are employed until retirement.

Individuals with different places of work and residence before retirement accept commuting costs. According to labor supply theory, at given earnings, commuting costs reduce the opportunity cost of leisure and therefore reduce labor supply (Cogan 1977, 1981). Gutiérrez-i-Puigarnau and van Ommeren (2010) assume a strict complementarity between commuting costs and labor supply. Their arguments for example on the negative effects of road pricing on labor supply however are based on the average employee situation in which males work full-time more often than females, commute relatively long distances, and are little affected by economic incentives with respect to their work participation (compare footnote 38 in Gutiérrez-i-Puigarnau and van Ommeren 2010). The insights from this paper on the impact of commuting costs and labor supply therefore may not apply for the decision to work after retirement. Given that older employees only work few hours and that they have a time perspective that is too short to look for a new home near a new employer, the necessity to (continue to) commute to a job after retirement may have a negative effect on labor supply. We therefore assume that potential commuting costs of individuals whose place of work is not the place of residence before retirement are higher. This group of employees therefore may be less attracted by financial incentives to work after retirement:

Hypothesis 6

Individuals whose place of work and residence is in the same region before retirement have higher earnings elasticities than individuals who have to commute.

Our last hypothesis concerns heterogeneity by income quartile before retirement. Bastani et al. (2021) show that earnings elasticity decreases with potential earnings. They argue that those with low potential earnings have a lower labor market attachment and therefore their potential for entry into the labor market is higher. For our group of old workers who have to decide whether to re-enter employment, this argument is not valid because their labor market attachment is zero when entering retirement. We however argue that the risk of having pension entitlements below the individual income aspiration level after retirement (“old-age poverty”) is higher for those with low labor earnings before retirement (Burkert and Hochfellner 2017). The financial aspect of work after retirement therefore may play a larger role for those who earned less before retirement (Fasbender et al. 2016):

Hypothesis 7

Individuals with lower earnings before retirement have higher earnings elasticities.

3 Data

Our analysis is based on a large and high-quality administrative dataset provided by the Federal Employment Agency in Germany (Bundesagentur für Arbeit). The data comprise a sample of 2% of employees from the Integrated Employment Biographies ranging from 1975 to 2014 (SIAB, 1975–2014).Footnote 9 Out data therefore only include employees subject to social security and employees in marginal employmentFootnote 10—civil and military servants (around five percent of the workforce) and self-employed (about ten percent of the workforce)Footnote 11 are excluded and unpaid care, household as well as volunteer work is not unfortunately unknown.

The data provide daily information about earnings and employment as well as receipt of benefits according to German Social Books II and III. Moreover, an extensive set of establishment information from the IAB Establishment History Panel is linked to the individual employment history. We know the day at which employees exit from the last employment subject to social insurance contributions before retirement or the day at which the bridge options end.Footnote 12 Individual and company-specific characteristics are measured at this point in time.

We know daily earnings of employees after retirement and whether an employee was in marginal employment or worked more. Earnings from marginal employment and pension entitlements are income tax free and do not require social security contributions in contrast to labor earnings beyond marginal employment.Footnote 13 We want to have comparable earnings indicators for employees in marginal employment and employees with higher earnings. We argue that disposable income is more relevant for the decision of whether to work or not than gross earnings. Therefore, we use net earnings after taxes and social contributions for labor earnings above the marginal employment threshold. More specifically, we deduct earnings taxes for earnings tax class 1, the solidarity surcharge, church tax and social security contributions to health and nursing care insurance. Approximately 80% of all employees are in marginal employment after retirement. The share of retired women who have labor earnings beyond the marginal employment level is with 18% somewhat smaller than the share of men (22%).

The age at which pensions can be received in Germany depends on the fact whether the individual is eligible for early retirement or not. There are several early retirement options that are tied to different requirements such as pension contribution years, gender, or disability. The most important early retirement options are the pension for long-term insured employees, pension for women, pension for severely disabled, and the two bridge options pension after unemployment and pension after partial retirement, see Lorenz et al. (2018) for an in-depth description of the early retirement rules and their changes over time. Individuals who are eligible for one or several early retirement options can exit the labor market and start to collect pensions at the ERA specified by the early retirement option (in many cases 60 or 63 years). All other individuals only can collect pensions at the NRA (65 years). People born after 1937 in addition can retire after the NRA. They receive a 6% increase in pension entitlements for each year of pension postponement.

We cannot observe when individuals start to receive pensions directly in our data and therefore define two groups with employment after receiving a pension. The first group consists of individuals who have a labor market spell after their NRA. The second group consists of individuals who already started a marginal employment before the age of 65 that extends beyond the age of 65 without interruption and who are eligible for early retirement.Footnote 14 We may incur three sources of measurement errors with this identification of individuals who work after retirement. First, some individuals work after NRA without receiving a pension. The number of employees who postponed their entry into retirement after NRA always was negligible.Footnote 15 We include these individuals because they are employed after NRA but incorrectly assume that they also draw pension benefits after age 65. Second, there may be individuals who receive pensions besides working but stop to work before age 65. We cannot observe this group of people and therefore our results only cover all individuals who work besides receiving retirement benefits after NRA. The third group works more than marginally before NRA in addition to receiving pensions. This group again is negligibly small because earnings beyond the threshold of marginal employment strongly reduce pension claims (Westermeier 2019). Unfortunately, there are no statistics on the incidence of this group.

3.1 Estimation sample

Our estimation sample consists of women and men born between 1935 and 1947. For each birth cohort, post-retirement employment is observed for a maximum of two years after the NRA. As work incidence quickly declines with age after 65 in Germany (compare for example Pfarr and Maier 2015), we are confident that we do not miss any retirees who start to work in retirement after their 67th birthday. We restrict our sample to West-GermanFootnote 16 men and women with a strong labor market attachment in old age. More specifically, all individuals in the sample must be employed subject to social security at least once after the age of 55Footnote 17 and they must be active in the labor market (employed, in partial retirement, or unemployed) at age 59.Footnote 18 The reason for these sample restrictions is to obtain a relatively homogeneous sample of employees who in principle all have the option to work after retirement. The restriction reduces our sample by about 30%.

It is relatively hard in Germany to return to the labor market after longer labor market gaps at higher age—in the group of employees excluded from our sample, the share or employees who work after retirement accordingly is less than one percent. Our sample restrictions also reduce the risk that we include individuals who also were civil servants or self-employed besides or after their employment subject to social security. There are age restrictions on starting a job with a civil servant status and it is hardly possible to work in a job subject to social security besides a job as civil servant. Employers usually do not allow their employees to generate a substantial income from self-employment besides their job subject to social security.

After the sample restrictions we are left with 30,784 women and 44,887 men—we therefore include 75,671 observations. In the sample, 6273 women and 9549 men continue to work after retirement, corresponding to an average of 20% for women and 21% for men, compare Appendix Table 7.Footnote 19 Across birth cohorts, the share of individuals who work beyond retirement has risen slightly. The number of observations and the share of individuals who continue to work after retirement by birth cohort are shown in Appendix Table 7.

Our data set has some drawbacks such as the absence of information on pension entry and other earnings sources beyond labor earnings and pension entitlements. It however has the advantage of including reliable and large-scale information on work behavior of older employees from many birth cohorts. Studies on the relationship between financial incentives and work beyond retirement so far typically relied on small-scale and potentially specific populations (Kim and Feldmann 2000; Saba and Guerin 2005; Torka et al. 2012) or on survey-based data that may be affected by self-selection and measurement error in key variables (Anger et al. 2018; Büsch et al. 2010; Dittrich et al. 2011; Kanabar 2015; Pfarr and Maier 2015, Saba and Guerin 2005).

3.2 Descriptive statistics

Our analysis focuses on labor and non-labor financial incentives for employment beyond retirement. The following descriptive statistics accordingly show average daily labor earnings, average pension entitlements, and the average share of labor earnings in pension entitlements by gender and type of employment after retirement (Table 1). The average daily net earnings after retirement are 14 EUR for women and 20 EUR for men.Footnote 20 For those who are marginally employed, daily earnings for both sexes are around 9 EUR. Pension entitlements of women who continue to work after retirement are on average 40% lower than those of men. Of particular interest is the share of labor earnings after retirement in pension entitlements. This share is quite substantial with 66% for women and 53% for men. For employees in marginal employment, the share is 47% for women and 27% for men. These findings are in line with evidence from the UK where labor earnings after retirement were more than 90% of average pension entitlements (Kanabar 2015). We therefore conclude that earnings after retirement are an important additional source of income for securing the standard of living in old age.Footnote 21

Table 1 Summary statistics on work and non-work earnings

We also can show that those who continue to work after retirement on average have a significantly lower pension entitlement than individuals who do not work after retirement (Appendix Table 8). This finding corresponds with the negative correlation between non-labor earnings and re-entry into employment after retirement found in most of the previous literature (Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Büsch et al. 2010; Dittrich et al. 2011; Hochfellner and Burkert 2013; Kim and Feldmann 2000; Micheel et al. 2010).Footnote 22 Appendix Table 8 also summarizes differences in individual and establishment characteristics prior to retirement between employees who continue to work after retirement and those who do not. This table shows, for example, that there is a negative correlation between work after retirement and employer size as well as the share of highly skilled workers.

4 Estimation strategy

We propose an empirical choice model to examine the decision on working after receiving a pension:

$$\begin{aligned} {\text{LFP}}_{{\text{i}}} =\upbeta _{0} + {\text{X}}_{{\text{i}}}\upbeta _{{\text{x}}} + {\text{Z}}_{{{\text{j}}\left( {\text{i}} \right)}}\upbeta _{{\text{z}}} +\upgamma {\text{pe}}_{{\text{i}}} +\updelta \widehat{wage}_{{\text{i}}} +\upvarepsilon _{{\text{i}}} \quad {\text{LFP}} & = 1\;{\text{ if}}\;{\text{LFP}}^{*} > 0 \\ \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad {\text{LFP}} & = 0 \;{\text{if}}\;{\text{LFP}}^{*} = 0 \\ \end{aligned}$$
(1)

The labor force participation variable (LFP) is a dichotomous variable with a value of zero for non-participation (no labor earnings) and a value of one (positive labor earnings) for employment after receiving a pension. The unobservable continuous variable “LFP*” reflects the utility difference between non-participation and participation in the labor market beyond retirement. Our main variables of interest are the log disposable pension entitlements “pe” (non-labor earnings) and the net (potential) labor earnings “wage” when receiving a pension.Footnote 23

Labor earnings after retirement may be endogenous because they also reflect time allocation decisions, that is, they are only observed for those who work after retirement. In order to circumvent this endogeneity problem, predicted daily labor earnings after retirement \(\widehat{wage}\) are estimated for all individuals in an auxiliary estimation. The standard Heckman sample selection approach (Heckman 1976, 1979) is used to predict the earnings of post-retirement employment. More specifically, we first estimate a reduced-form post-retirement employment participation Probit model for all individuals in the sample. We use the Probit parameters from this participation equation to generate the inverse Mills ratio. Including this ratio controls for possible sample-selection bias in the wage equation. We then take the results of the wage equation to generate values of the predicted wage for all individuals in the sample (Borra 2010).

Technically, this type of selectivity corrected model can achieve identification by functional form assumptions (Cameron and Trivedi 2002). Nonetheless, most researchers feel more comfortable if at least one regressor in the participation equation is excluded from the labor earnings equation (Connelly and Kimmel 2003; Borra 2010). We accordingly include in the reduced form labor participation equation as exclusion restriction the accumulated pension entitlements. Pension entitlements indicate the negative income effect in the participation equation and they are an indicator of past labor market performance. Given that all employees obtain a new labor contract, usually entailing less labor hours and new tasks, previous labor market performance is hardly related to (potential) earnings after retirement, compare Appendix Table 9. Pension entitlements therefore can be excluded from the earnings equation.

Besides the exclusion restriction and the Mills ratio in the earnings equation, we include core individual characteristics that have been used in the literature as determinants of work after retirement (Anger et al. 2018; Brenke 2013; Brussig 2010; Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Engstler and Romeu-Gordo 2017; Fasbender et al. 2016; Hofäcker and Naumann 2015; Larsen and Pedersen 2013; Maestas 2010; Micheel et al. 2017; Rhein 2016; Westermeier 2019). More specifically, we include education, occupation,Footnote 24 accumulated labor market gaps until age 65 in months,Footnote 25 and the year of labor market exit. We keep the auxiliary regressions parsimonious in order to avoid multicollinearity problems in our main labor participation regression (Borra 2010).

In the main labor participation equation, we include all explanatory variables used in the auxiliary participation equations and (potential) labor earnings. In addition, we include dummies that equal one if an individual uses the bridge option partial retirement or unemployment because labor market gaps before retirement negatively affect the continuation of employment after retirement (Anger et al. 2018; Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Schellenberg et al. 2005; Smeaton and McKay 2003; Westermeier 2019). We also include several characteristics of the last employer before retirement. Previous studies have shown that employees in small establishments have a higher probability of working beyond retirement (Anger et al. 2018; Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Micheel et al. 2010). In addition, Brussig and Bellmann (2008) show that attitudes towards hiring older workers differ among companies. For example, employees in companies with a high proportion of older employees have a higher chance of being hired after their retirement than those in companies with a high proportion of employees in partial retirement and severance payments. Moreover, some studies also use the general economic environment as a determinant of employment after retirement. We therefore include the mean imputed earnings of all full-time employees, economic sector, establishment size, share of employees in partial retirement, share of highly qualified employees, share of employees aged 55–59, share of employees aged 60–64, and the share of employees aged 65 and older.

We take into account that the decision to work after retirement is fundamentally different between men and women because the non-market production situation usually differs between the genders. We therefore estimate all earnings and participation equations separately for men and women.

5 Estimation results

5.1 Employment decision to work beyond retirement

The first estimation step, the calculation of the earnings equation for all individuals in our sample, is shown in Appendix Table 10. We use potential earnings for individuals who do not work after retirement from this estimation. In the earnings equations, selectivity of employees who decide to work after retirement is taken in account by including the Mills’ ratio (“lambda”) derived from the parsimonious first-step labor market participation equation. The Hausman specification test checks whether our exclusion restriction is valid to control for endogeneity. The high χ2 values indicate that the pension entitlements variable is a valid exclusion restriction for the labor market participation equation.

We present our estimation results of the second estimation step, the decision to work beyond retirement, in Table 2, separately for women (column I) and men (column II). The OLS estimates suggest a substantial positive effect of the (potential) earnings on labor supply for women and men. According to Hypothesis 1, an increase in (potential) labor earnings by one percent significantly increases the probability of being active in the labor force by 0.056 percentage points for women and by 0.246 percentage points for men, respectively. In other words, an increase in (potential) labor earnings by 10% has the potential to increase labor market participation of men from their average 20.5% (see Appendix Table 7) to about 23% and of women from 19.3% to almost 20%. According to Hypothesis 4, labor earnings elasticity is much higher for men than for women.Footnote 26 Consistent with Hypothesis 2, an increase in pension entitlements by one percent significantly reduces the employment probability by 0.055 percentage points for women and 0.165 percentage points for men. Hochfellner and Burkert (2013) find a similar pattern by gender, their income elasticities are however somewhat lower. Pleau and Shauman (2013) find a smaller negative effect of retirement income on working after retirement for males than for females in their US sample, however. A higher pension entitlement leads to a stronger reduction in labor market participation for men than for women, accordingly.

Table 2 Linear probability model of labor force participation

The individual characteristics show the expected signs on employment after retirement (compare for example Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Larsen and Pedersen 2013; Maestas 2010): employees who use bridge paths have a significantly lower probability to work and therefore labor market gaps before retirement have a negative correlation with labor market participation after retirement. Academics work less after retirement than skilled employees. Occupations before retirement hardly have an influence on working after retirement, however.Footnote 27

These are the effects of the establishment characteristics of the last employer prior to retirement on the labor market decision of the retiree: workers who are employed in firms with more than ten employees prior to retirement show a lower labor force participation after retirement. Furthermore, there is a negative correlation between mean earnings of all full-time employees, the share of highly qualified employees, and the share of employees in partial retirement and work after retirement. The higher the share of employees who work after retirement at the last employer, the higher is the probability of being employed after retirement.

Note that the (potential) labor earnings regressor is generated because it has been estimated in a separate step with uncertainty (Borra 2010). Therefore, the standard errors of this variable are bootstrapped. A bivariate Probit model is used to verify the results of the linear probability model presented in Table 2. The results of both estimation models are consistent with each other.

The estimation equation in Table 3 replaces the separate labor earnings and pension entitlement variables by the share of earnings in disposable income. This variable has a substantial positive impact on the extensive margin of labor supply. An increase in the share of (potential) labor earnings in disposable income after retirement by one percentage point increases the probability of working beyond retirement by 0.22 percentage points for women and 0.82 percentage points for men. This result supports Hypothesis 3.

Table 3 Linear probability model of labor force participation with the share of estimated earnings in disposable income

5.2 Heterogeneity in earnings elasticities

Table 4 shows differences in the estimated elasticity of labor force participation with respect to (potential) labor earnings between employees who use bridge paths versus those who do not use bridge paths prior to retirement. In line with Hypothesis 5 and prior empirical evidence (Anger et al. 2018; Burkert and Hochfellner 2017; Hochfellner and Burkert 2013), the estimates suggest a higher positive earnings effect on labor supply for employees without bridge paths than for employees with bridge paths. The earnings elasticities for employees without a bridge path are twice as large for women and 50% larger for men than those for employees with bridge paths, see Table 5. Employees without bridge paths therefore seem to derive lower utility from leisure and they are more responsive to financial incentives when deciding about employment after retirement.

Table 4 Extensive margin of labor supply for employees with and without bridge paths
Table 5 Extensive margin of labor supply for employees whose region of residence is the same as or different from the place of work

When we compare earnings elasticities between employees who have to commute to work to a different region in their last employment prior to retirement and those who live and work in the same region, we use the approach proposed by Kropp and Schwengler (2016) to delineate 50 functional West German labor market regions based on commuting flows.Footnote 28 The dummy has value one if an employee commutes to a workplace outside the own labor market region. Our results do not support Hypothesis 6: there are practically no differences between commuters and non-commuters for females and the differences between both employee groups are small for men, see Table 6.Footnote 29 We hardly find changes in the commuting situation before and after retirement. Commuting costs therefore seem not to play a central role for the labor supply decision of older employees for example in comparison to financial needs of older employees.

Table 6 Extensive margin of labor supply for employees with low and high earnings before retirement

Our last sample split differentiates employees according to their earnings situation before exiting the labor market into retirement. According to Hypothesis 7, we find a higher elasticity of men in the lowest earnings quartile in comparison to men in the highest earnings quartile. For women, the lowest and highest earnings quartiles both have lower elasticities than the second and third earnings quartiles and therefore Hypothesis 7 is not supported for women. Our evidence only is in accordance with findings by Pleau (2010) and Pleau and Shauman (2013) for US men. They however find an increasing labor market supply elasticity with pre-retirement earnings for US women. The low labor supply elasticity of women with very low earnings before retirement may be a consequence of high alternative financial sources for example from other household members that we cannot observe in our data (Blundell et al. 2007; Micheel et al. 2010).

6 Discussion and limitations

Our paper uses the empirical identification approach developed for the employment decision of women with small children (Allègre et al. 2015; Borra 2010; Rammohan and Whelan 2007; Ribar 1992; Viitanen 2005). This literature mainly uses structural estimation models because there are hardly any quasi-natural experiments that can be exploited to obtain causal relationships between financial incentives and the employment decision.Footnote 30 Also the literature on determinants for work after retirement usually does not exploit quasi-natural experiments (Chetty et al. 2011). The main reason for the dearth of quasi-experimental evidence is that there were hardly any changes in the rules for labor earnings after retirement. In Germany, earnings beyond marginal employment have to be taxed at the common rates, marginal employment is tax free and the maximum earnings level for marginal employment was practically unchanged.Footnote 31 In 2005, a pension supplement of 6% per year of retirement after NRA was introduced for all pension entitlements. This option was used by a negligible share of retirees, however.

Besides using a structural approach our study is limited by several gaps in relevant information. Our data set does not report hours worked and we therefore only could analyze the extensive margin. Future work, as a consequence, should analyze retiree´s labor supply respect to the number of hours worked conditional on employment (intensive margin). In addition, our administrative data only include pension entitlements derived from labor earnings. Future work therefore should include additional available financial means during retirement such as occupation pensions, additional pension entitlements for example from raising children or rent from wealth, assets, and real estate. Also considerable financial demands such as mortgage debt or financially dependent household have an important impact on the decision to work that is unobservable for us. Moreover, decisions about labor supply after retirement may result from considerations involving other individuals such as pension redistributions after a divorce or widow/widower pensions. Especially equivalent household income may be a more important driver for work after retirement than the individual financial situation. We know in addition that males and females react differently to financial stimuli within the household context (Blundell et al. 2007; Micheel et al. 2010). The distribution of wage elasticities of single childless women is very similar to that of men. It therefore is mainly married women and mothers who have higher wage elasticities (Bargain and Peichl 2016). As a consequence, also the household and marital situation and changes in behavior of household members not affected by financial incentive changes should be included in future research in order to get a full and unbiased picture of financial incentives for work after retirement.

Transferability of our results to other countries depends on the empirical question whether there are differences in labor supply elasticities between countries. It seems that there are little international differences in work preference (Bargain et al. 2014), although there for example were marked differences with respect to the role of women on the labor market and in the household between East and West Germany before and shortly after the reunification of both countries (Sprengholz et al. 2020). In addition, there seems to be a secular reduction in wage elasticities over the last decades in many countries (Bargain and Peichl 2016). It therefore remains unclear what the influence of the observation period and institutional differences is for estimations of labor supply elasticities in other countries or in the Eastern part of Germany.

7 Conclusions

This paper provides a labor supply model for retirees and empirical assessments based on a large administrative labor market history data set. We for the first time use detailed information about labor earnings and non-labor income of a large administrative 2% sample of all employees after their retirement in Germany. We concentrate on the effect of labor earnings on the labor force participation beyond retirement and take endogeneity of the labor decision and heterogeneities between different employee groups into account.

We first establish that labor earnings achieved by pensioners after retirement constitute a substantial part of disposable income. The share of post-retirement earnings in disposable income is more than 60% for women and 50% for men. We then show that men are more responsive to financial incentives than women. A one percent increase in (potential) post-retirement labor earnings increases the employment probability of pensioners by 0.246 percentage points for males and by 0.056 percentage points for females. Labor earnings therefore have a strong incentive effect for work after retirement. Higher pension entitlements however lead to a negative labor participation effect. We analogously find that the higher the share of (potential) labor earnings in disposable income of the retiree, the higher is the labor force participation of the individual. We also show that individuals who work until retirement instead of using the bridge options unemployment or partial retirement as well as men with low earnings prior to retirement are stronger attracted by (potential) earnings incentives to work after retirement. Having to commute before retirement in contrast to residing in the same region as the place of work does not influence work participation after retirement, however.

Our analysis therefore shows that tax incentives or higher earnings offers by employers are most effective to stimulate labor market participation after retirement for males who earned not much before retirement and did not use bridge options. The calculation of the separate elasticities for labor earnings and pension eligibilities for example allows us the prediction of changes in financial incentives on work supply after retirement for different demographic groups. More specifically, our analysis shows that the gradual reduction of tax-free allowance to zero until 2040 that was induced by the Retirement Income Act 2004 (Genser and Holzmann 2019) may increase incentives to work after retirement. We also show that an increase in the tax-free allowance for work during pension also may have a positive effect for the older employees affected by the measure.

8 Methods

On the basis of theoretical hypotheses derived from a labor supply model, we propose an empirical choice model to examine the employment decision after receiving a pension. The decision to participate in the labor market is estimated based on a linear probability model using the employment status after retirement as the outcome variable. In order to impute (potential) labor earnings for all individuals included in the sample as explanatory variable, a two-step Heckman-type selection model is used. For the estimations, a sample of 2% of employees from the Integrated Employment Biographies from 1975 to 2014 (SIAB, 1975–2014) is used.

Availability of data and materials

The paper uses the SIAB7514. Data access was provided via on site use at the Research Data Centre (FDZ) of the German Federal Employment Agency (BA) at the Institute for Employment Research (IAB) and subsequently via remote data access. These data are publicly available.

Notes

  1. Also in Germany, the labor force participation rate of people aged 65 to 74 increased to 9.6% in 2014 from 4.2% in 2002, implying a rise of almost 140% (Rhein 2016).

  2. Examples are the German Ageing Survey (Deutscher Alterssurvey DEAS) or the Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in. Europe (SHARE).

  3. We only briefly summarize the literature on the impact of financial situation on working after retirement. There are several recent literature reviews that describe the knowledge about other drivers, compare for example Engstler and Romeu-Gordo (2014) or Sullivan and Al Ariss (2019).

  4. Please note that “not working” when receiving an old-age pension means for many individual in our dataset to be engaged in unpaid care, household or volunteer work or being self-employed.

  5. Please note that the concept of bridge employment in Germany differs from that used in the US (Beehr and Bennett 2015). In Germany, bridge employment means that employees exit employment earlier then retirement or reduce their working time in their career job or they exit into unemployment from their career job before they enter retirement. In the US, bridge employment usually means taking another job after their career job.

  6. Almost all employees in bridge options in the cohorts we look at also are entitled to use other early retirement options such as the pension for women and the pension for the long-term insured. Indeed, many employees in bridge options used these alternative early retirement options after their bridge option.

  7. Erlinghagen (2005) and Ullmann and Bothfeld (2008) show that the average share of involuntary job terminations was between 20 and 30 percent after 1996 and that the share of involuntary job terminations was strongly negatively correlated with age.

  8. This assumption of course applies under the ceteris paribus assumption. We know that partial retirement is mainly accepted by better educated employees who work for large (industrial) employers (Engstler and Romeu-Gordo 2017) and bridge options are mainly offered by employers with higher employee adaptation costs, i.e. large but shrinking employers in regions with high unemployment (Lorenz et al. 2020). It is therefore important to control for the mentioned individual and employer characteristics in order to avoid biased results.

  9. A detailed description of the SIAB can be found in Antoni et al. (2016).

  10. Marginal employment is defined as dependent employment with a maximum monthly salary of 400 EUR (raised to 450 EUR in 2013).

  11. The employment shares have been taken from Institut für Arbeit und Qualifikation (2020).

  12. In Germany, it is compulsory to report the end of employment to the social insurance system after the statutory retirement age. In the case of employment after retirement, the employer must provide a new contract and submit a new declaration to the social insurance, even if the employee was already employed by the company. Thus, employment is interrupted after pension entry by 1 day (Burkert and Hochfellner 2017).

  13. Tax and deduction exemptions on marginal employment were abolished just in 2012.

  14. The SIAB data do not include relevant characteristics of the pension insurance, such as pension entitlements or eligibility. Therefore, individual pension entitlements are calculated and eligibility criteria for old age pensions and the corresponding statutory retirement dates NRA and ERA are identified according to Pfister et al. (2018) and Lorenz et al. (2018). We are grateful to Philip vom Berge and Dana Müller from the FDZ at the IAB for merging the day of birth as part of the Custom Shaped Administrative Data for the Analysis of Labor Market (CADAL) project because the calculation of pension entitlements requires the exact birth date.

  15. Bäcker et al. (2017) for example report that in 2014, from about 825,000 retired individuals only about two percent or 22,000 individuals received a bonus.

  16. Labor market careers are only available for East Germany after January 1, 1991 (Antoni et al. 2016).

  17. This sample restriction was also made by Hanel (2010) and Geyer et al. (2021).

  18. We also exclude seamen and miners (less than one percent of women and of men) because they have special protection of legitimate expectation rules for retirement that cannot be identified in the dataset.

  19. The proportion of employees who continue to work after retirement is slightly lower than that calculated by Anger et al. (2018). In their study, however, employment after retirement is identified from survey answers. The share of older employees who indicate that they intend to work after retirement in surveys even is between a third and a half (Micheel et al. 2010; Micheel 2021).

  20. Women have no earnings after retirement above the social contribution earnings threshold and for men the proportion with earnings above the earnings threshold is 0.3%. We therefore do not have to correct for censored earnings.

  21. Please note that we cannot take into account other sources of income, such as private and occupation pensions, capital and real estate rents, independent work or savings.

  22. Two studies from Germany (Anger et al. 2018; Pfarr and Maier 2015) and one study from England (Kanabar 2015) however show that employees with higher financial means are more likely to work beyond retirement.

  23. In a further estimation specification, instead of the expected earnings and the pension entitlements, the ratio of the (potential) earnings in pension entitlements is included in the equation.

  24. The Blossfeld classification of occupations is intended to form occupational groups as homogeneously as possible with regard to average educational and vocational background and professional fields of activity (Blossfeld 1985).

  25. An alternative for the aggregated gaps in the labor market before the age of 65 is the exit age from employment before the statutory retirement age. The results are robust. It is not possible to include both variables in the estimations because they are strongly correlated. Early retirement is associated with more gaps in the labor market before the age of 65.

  26. We obtain larger coefficients for the estimated earnings variables in the labor participation equation if we drop the endogeneity correction (Mills ratio) in the earnings estimation step. (Potential) earnings however remain significant and larger for men than for women without controlling for endogeneity.

  27. All results remain robust when only individual characteristics are included in the participation equation and employer characteristics are not controlled for.

  28. The labor market regions are defined based on the place of work and the residential regions are defined based on the place of residence at the last employment prior to retirement.

  29. The results remain robust when the information about place of work and place of residence are directly used from the dataset instead of the approach proposed by Kropp and Schwengler (2016).

  30. A notable exception is Bastani et al. (2021) who analyze the impact of a change in labor market participation tax rates on labor supply of secondary earners.

  31. The maximum earnings level for minimum employment was increased on 1 January 2013 from 400€ to 450€, but further unchanged during our observation period.

References

  • Allègre, G., Simonnet, V., Sofer, C.: Child care and labor market participation in France: do monetary incentives matter? Ann. Econ. Stat. 117(118), 115–139 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anger, S., Trahms, A., Westermeier, C.: Erwerbstätigkeit nach dem Übergang in Altersrente: Soziale Motive überwiegen, aber auch Geld ist wichtig. IAB-Kurzbericht, 24/2018. Nuremberg (2018)

  • Antoni, M., Ganzer, A., vom Berge, P.: Stichprobe der Integrierten Arbeitsmarktbiografien (SIAB) 1975–2014. FDZ Datenreport, 04/2016. Nuremberg (2016)

  • Bäcker, G., Jansen, A., Schmitz, J.: Rente erst ab 70? Probleme und Perspektiven des Altersübergangs. IAQ-Forschung 2017-02. University of Duisburg-Essen (2017)

  • Bargain, O., Orsini, K., Peichl, A.: Comparing labor supply elasticities in Europe and the United States—new results. J. Hum. Resour. 49(3), 723–838 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargain, O., Peichl, A.: Own-wage labor supply elasticities: variation across time and estimation methods. IZA J. Labor Econ. 5(10), 1–31 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bastani, S., Moberg, Y., Selin, H.: The anatomy of the extensive margin labor supply response. Scand. J. Econ. 123(1), 33–59 (2021)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beehr, T., Bennett, M.: Working after retirement: features of bridge employment and research directions. Work Aging Retire. 1(1), 112–128 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, F., Kahn, L.: Changes in the labor supply behavior of married women: 1980–2000. J. Law Econ. 25(3), 393–438 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  • Blossfeld, H.P.: Berufseintritt und Berufsverlauf. Mitt. Arbeitsmarkt Berufsforsch. 18(2), 177–197 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Chiappori, P., Magnac, T., Meghir, C.: Collective labour supply: heterogeneity and non-participation. Rev. Econ. Stud. 74(2), 417–445 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borra, C.: Childcare costs and Spanish mothers’ labor force participation. Hacienda Pública Española/revista De Economía Pública 194(3), 9–40 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Brenke, K.: Immer mehr Menschen im Rentenalter sind berufstätig. DIW Wochenbericht 80(6), 3–12 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Brussig, M.: Erwerbstätigkeit im Alter hängt vom Beruf ab. Altersübergangs-Report, 2010-05. University of Duisburg-Essen (2010)

  • Brussig, M.: Alter beim Austritt aus sozialversicherungspflichtiger Beschäftigung ist gestiegen. Altersübergangs-Report, 2015-01 (2015)

  • Brussig, M., Bellmann, L.: Betriebliche Einflussfaktoren auf Rekrutierungen Älterer und deren Bewerbungen. German J. Hum. Resour. Manag. 22(1), 35–57 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burkert, C., Hochfellner, D.: Employment trajectories beyond retirement. J. Aging Soc. Policy 29(2), 143–167 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Büsch, V., Dorbritz, J., Heien, T., Micheel, F.: Weiterbeschäftigung im Rentenalter: Wünsche, Bedingungen, Möglichkeiten. Materialien zur Bevölkerungswissenschaft, 129/2010 (2010)

  • Cahill, K., Giandrea, M., Quinn, J.: Retirement patterns and the macroeconomy, 1992–2010: the prevalence and determinants of bridge jobs, phased retirement, and reentry among three recent cohorts of older Americans. Gerontologist 55(3), 384–403 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cahuc, P., Carcillo, S., Zylberberg, A.: Labor Economics. MIT press, Cambridge (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, C., Trivedi, P.: Microeconometrics—Methods and Applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R., Guren, A., Manoli, D., Weber A.: Does indivisible labor explain the difference between micro and macro elasticities? A meta-analysis of extensive margin elasticities. NBER Working Paper 16729. Cambridge MA (2011)

  • Cogan, J.F.: Labor supply with time and money costs of participation. Rand Report R-2044-HEW. Santa Monica CA (1977)

  • Cogan, J.F.: Fixed costs and labor supply. Econometrica 49(4), 945–963 (1981)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, R.: The effect of child care costs on married women’s labor force participation. Rev. Econ. Stat. 74(1), 83–90 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, R., Kimmel, J.: Marital status and full-time/part-time work status in child care choices. Appl. Econ. 35(7), 761–777 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Boca, D., Vuri, D.: The mismatch between employment and child care in Italy: the impact of rationing. J. Popul. Econ. 20(4), 805–832 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittrich, D., Büsch, V., Micheel, F.: Working beyond retirement age in Germany: the employee’s perspective. In: Ennals, R., Salomon, R. (eds.) Older Workers in a Sustainable Society, pp. 189–202. Peter Lang, Frankfurt am Main (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Engstler, H., Romeu-Gordo, L.: Arbeiten im Ruhestand—Entwicklung, Faktoren und Motive der Erwerbstätigkeit von Altersrentenbeziehern. In: Kistler, E., Trischler, F. (eds) Reformen auf dem Arbeitsmarkt und in der Alterssicherung—Folgen für die Einkunftslage im Alter. edition der Hans-Böckler-Stiftung, Arbeit und Soziales 196, Düsseldorf, pp. 115–147 (2014)

  • Engstler, H., Romeu-Gordo, L.: Der Übergang in den Ruhestand: Alter, Pfade und Ausstiegspläne. In: Mahne, K., Wolff, C., Simonson, J., Tesch-Römer, C. (eds.) Altern im Wandel, pp. 65–80. Springer, Wiesbaden (2017)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Erlinghagen, M.: Entlassungen und Beschäftigungssicherheit im Zeitverlauf. Z. Soziol. 34(2), 147–168 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eurofound: Income From Work After Retirement in the EU. Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Evers, M., De Mooij, R., van Vuuren, D.: What explains the variation in estimates of labor supply elasticities? Ifo Institute for Economic Research Working Paper Series, 1633. Munich (2005)

  • Fasbender, U., Wang, M., Voltmer, J.B., Deller, J.: The meaning of work for postretirement employment decisions. Work Aging Retire. 2(1), 12–23 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Genser, B. Holzmann, R.: Taxing German old-age pensions fairly and efficiently, ifo DICE report volume 17. Munich (2019)

  • Geyer, J., Haan, P., Lorenz, S., Zwick, T. Bruns, M.: The role of labor demand in the labor market effects of pension reforms. Industrial Relations, forthcoming (2021)

  • Grund, C.: Severance payments for dismissed employees in Germany. Eur. J. Law Econ. 22(1), 49–71 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gutiérrez-i-Puigarnau, E., van Ommeren, J.: Labour supply and commuting. J. Urban Econ. 68(1), 82–89 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanel, B.: Financial incentives to postpone retirement and further effects on employment—evidence from a natural experiment. Labour Econ. 17(3), 474–486 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hank, K., Buber, I.: Grandparents caring for their grandchildren: findings from the 2004 survey of health, ageing, and retirement in Europe. J. Fam. Issues 30(1), 53–73 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J.: The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models. Ann. Econ. Soc. Meas. 5(4), 475–492 (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J.: Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47(1), 153–161 (1979)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hochfellner, D., Burkert, C.: Berufliche Aktivität im Ruhestand. Z. Gerontol. Geriatr. 46(3), 242–250 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofäcker, D., Naumann, E.: The emerging trend of work beyond retirement age in Germany. Z. Gerontol. Geriatr. 48(5), 473–479 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Institut für Arbeit und Qualifikation.: Erwerbstätige nach Stellung im Beruf 1994–2019. Sozialpolitik aktuell in Deutschland, University of Duisburg-Essen (2020)

  • Kanabar, R.: Post-retirement labour supply in England. J. Econ. Ageing 6, 123–132 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S., Feldmann, D.C.: Working in retirement: the antecedents of bridge employment and its consequences for quality of life in retirement. Acad. Manag. J. 43(6), 1195–1210 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Komp, K., van Tilburg, T., Broese van Groenou, M.: Paid work between age 60 and 70 years in Europe: a matter of socio-economic status? Int. J. Ageing Later Life 5(1), 45–75 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kropp, P., Schwengler, B.: Three-step method for delineating functional labor market regions. Reg. Stud. 50(3), 429–445 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larsen, M., Pedersen, P.: To work, to retire- or both? Labor market activity after 60. IZA J. Eur. Labor Stud. 2, 21 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz, S., Pfister, M., Zwick T.: Identification of the statutory retirement dates in the Sample of Integrated Labor Market Biographies (SIAB). FDZ Methodenreport, 08/2018. Nuremberg (2018)

  • Lorenz, S., Pfister, M., Zwick, T.: Beware of the employer: financial incentives for employees may fail to prolong old-age employment. ZEW Discussion Paper, 20-007. Mannheim (2020)

  • Maestas, N.: Back to work: expectations and realizations of work after retirement. J. Hum. Resour. 45(3), 718–748 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxin, L., Deller, J.: Activities in retirement: individual experience of silver work. Comp. Popul. Stud. 35(4), 801–832 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, B., Rosenbaum, D.: Welfare, the earned income tax credit, and the labor supply of single mothers. Q. J. Econ. 116(3), 1063–1114 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Micheel, F.: The intention to paid and/or unpaid activities in retirement—a study of older workers in Germany. J. Aging Soc. Policy 33(2), 101–119 (2021)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Micheel, F., Cihlar, V., Riedl, S.: “Der Geist ist willig, aber...”—Was Menschen daran hindert, im Ruhestand zu arbeiten. Bevölkerungsforschung Aktuell, 6/2017, 2–9 (2017)

  • Micheel, F., Roloff, J., Wickenheiser, I.: The impact of socioeconomic characteristics on older employees’ willingness to continue working in retirement age. Comp. Popul. Stud. Zeitschrift Für Bevölkerungswissenschaft 35(4), 869–902 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J.: Labor force participation of married women. In: Lewis, H. (ed.) Aspect of Labor Economics. Universities National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Series, vol. 14, pp. 63–105. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1962)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfarr, C., Maier, C.: Arbeit trotz Rente: Warum bleiben Menschen in Ruhestand erwerbstätig. Deutsches Institut für Altersvorsorge, Berlin (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfister, M., Lorenz, S., Zwick, T.: Implementation of pension entitlements in the sample of integrated labor market biographies (SIAB). FDZ Methodenreport, 01/2018. Nuremberg (2018)

  • Pleau, R.: Gender differences in postretirement employment. Res. Aging 32(3), 267–303 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pleau, R., Shauman, K.: Trends and correlates of post-retirement employment, 1977–2009. Hum. Relat. 66(1), 113–141 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rammohan, A., Whelan, S.: The Impact of childcare costs on the full-time/part-time employment decisions of Australian mothers. Australian Economic Papers 46(2), 152–169 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasner, A., Etgeton, S.: Rentenübergangspfade: Reformen haben großen Einfluss. DIW-Wochenbericht 81(19), 431–441 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rhein, T.: Arbeiten im Rentenalter: Erwerbstätigkeit 65plus in Europa. Aktuelle Berichte, 25/2016. Institute for Employment Research, Nuremberg (2016)

  • Ribar, D.C.: Child care and the labor supply of married women: reduced form evidence. J. Hum. Resour. 27(1), 134–165 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson, R., Wallenius, J.: Micro and macro elasticities in a life cycle model with taxes. J. Econ. Theory 144(6), 2277–2292 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saba, T., Guerin, G.: Extending employment beyond retirement age: the case of health care managers in Quebec. Public Pers. Manag. 34, 195–214 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schellenberg, G., Turcotte, M., Ram, B.: Post-retirement employment. Stat. Can. Perspect. 75–001, 14–17 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmähl, W.: Ageing workforce: firm strategies and public policy in Germany. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. 28(4), 575–595 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smeaton, D., McKay, S.: Working after state pension age: quantitative analysis. UK Department for Work and Pensions Research Report 182. London (2003)

  • Sprengholz, M., Wieber, A., Holst, E.: Gender identity and wives’ labor market outcomes in West and East Germany between 1983 and 2016. Socio-Econ. Rev. (2020). https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwaa048

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan, S.E., Al Ariss, A.: Employment after retirement: a review and framework for future research. J. Manag. 45(1), 262–284 (2019)

    Google Scholar 

  • Torka, N., Goedegebure, I., Van Ewijk, I., Looise, J.: On the motives and needs for work beyond age 65: comparing voluntary workers versus agency workers. German J. Hum. Resour. Manag. 26(2), 167–188 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ullmann, K., Bothfeld, S.: The German employment protection act—how does it work in company practice? WSI Discussion Paper 161, Duesseldorf (2008)

  • Vargha, L., Gál, R., Crosby-Nagy, M.: Household production and consumption over the life cycle: national time transfer accounts in 14 European countries. Demogr. Res. 36(32), 905–944 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viitanen, T.K.: Cost of childcare and female employment in the UK. Labour 19, 149–170 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, M., Zhan, Y., Liu, S., Shultz, K.: Antecedents of bridge employment: a longitudinal investigation. J. Appl. Psychol. 93(4), 818–830 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wanger, S.: Altersteilzeit: Beliebt, aber nicht zukunftsgerecht. IAB-Kurzbericht, 08/2009 (2009)

  • Westermeier, C.: Ältere am Arbeitsmarkt. Eine stabile Beschäftigung vor dem Rentenalter begünstigt die Weiterarbeit. IAB-Kurzbericht, 15/2019 (2019)

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Mona Bruns for helpful discussions on this paper.

Funding

Not applicable.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Both authors contributed in equal shares to the paper. Both authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Zwick.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Not applicable.

Competing interests

Not applicable.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 7, 8, 9, and 10.

Table 7 Number and share of individuals who work beyond retirement by birth cohort
Table 8 Sample characteristics
Table 9 Correlations between previous labor market experience and estimated as well as observed earnings
Table 10 Auxiliary estimations

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lorenz, S., Zwick, T. Money also is sunny in a retiree’s world: financial incentives and work after retirement. J Labour Market Res 55, 21 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1186/s12651-021-00304-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s12651-021-00304-1

Keywords

JEL Classification